Sunday, February 12, 2017

A Look at Positive Labeling and its Impact on the Educational Trajectories of Students **DO NOT COPY**

A Look at Positive Labeling and its Impact on the Educational Trajectories of Students
Gabriela Monasterio



Northeastern University Political Science Department

            In education, labels are applied to everyone, whether it is explicit or implied. Children with learning disabilities (LDs), those with behavioral issues, “average” students, and the gifted are all labeled, and each of these labels has a meaning associated with it. Labels tell us how we should act around others, and our labels change how others treat us. In education, this can be the difference between success and failure, or between getting accepted or rejected from a university.  In one experiment involving young children, a randomly selected group was labeled as “spurters,” or those about to experience an intellectual growth spurt. The students labeled as spurters showed a greater increase in IQ over the year, despite being randomly selected (Rosenthal and Jacobson, 1968). This is known as the Pygmalion effect, and this effect is most pronounced in marginalized groups, including women and minorities. This inspired the following research, which surveyed the population of the Northeastern University freshman dorm International Village. The opposing force to the Pygmalion effect is stereotype threat, where minorities perform worse on average when reminded of the stereotypes that label them as inferior or when the “stigmatized identities were activated” (Thompson, 2014).  Although these examples deal with education and positive labeling, the vast majority of the literature does not deal with positive labeling, and much of it deals with LDs and behavioral disorders.
            When dealing with LDs, the literature is conflicted, as many students have multiple disorders or mitigating factors, so the additional labeling may push them back further instead of helping them (Moniqueka and Heraldo, 2012). Several studies involving labeling video or paper descriptions of students resulted in conflicting conclusions, with Batzel et al, and Harvey & Pellock concluding that labels influence the way teachers perceive a student, and Boucher, and Cornett-Ruiz & Hendricks concluding that labels do not overwhelmingly influence teachers (Ayers, Krueger and Jones, 2015). A 2013 study looked at the outcomes of the students diagnosed with LDs, and the real causes behind their outcomes. It was concluded that the outcomes were a combination of self-stigmatization, their deficiencies, direct stigmatization, and cumulative disadvantage (Shifrer, 2013).
            One study that did involve positive labels looked at the correlation between a mother’s praise and her student’s performance in school, but the results were quite strange. Although the praise increased the child’s perception of their intelligence, it decreased their likelihood to take on challenges (Pomerantz and Kempner, 2013). To the average observer, those seem contrary, but Pomerantz and Kempner concluded that greater perceived intelligence in children was inversely correlated to effort in those children. In the following research, The goal was to fill in the gaps that these studies have left; what correlation does positive labeling have on students once they have exited the K-12 school system?  
Methods
            The Northeastern University dorm was surveyed door-to-door between floors 2 and 9 using a 1-page front and back written survey. The survey was completed between the hours of 8 and 11:30 on a weeknight. This time was chosen because it was between normal dinner hours and before quiet hours, so the researcher surmised that the most students would be in their dorm rooms or common areas between those hours. The survey was posed as an optional break from studying or way to procrastinate further on assignments being ignored, and as a way to help a fellow student.  Respondents were asked about their experiences being labeled, and asked to provide specific details about the first instance of labeling. They were also asked about their college applications and acceptances in order to see the effects of the labeling. The respondents were also asked a panel of questions to measure their self-esteem (Rosenberg, 1965). For classification purposes, respondents were also asked their race, ethnicity, age, and the race they are perceived to be by others. The full battery of questions can be found in figure 3, and the responses can be found in table 2.
            An attempt was made to sample each floor equally, and all sections of the dorm were sampled equally other than 5th floor West side, and 9th floor West side, both with no responses. In total, 57 students were surveyed, and 4 of those were omitted due to incomplete surveys. All respondents were freshmen attending Northeastern University, and all respondents were members of the Honors College.
            The data were inputted by hand and then analyzed using Microsoft Excel.
Hypotheses
1.     If the student was positively labeled before the age of 10 and was not told they were below average, then the student would be admitted to more colleges and honors programs compared to those labeled after the age of 10
2.     If the student was negatively labeled, they will have lower self-esteem than those who were not negatively labeled.
Results
            Of the 53 complete responses, all 53 had been labeled positively, and only 3 had been labeled negatively in addition to being labeled positively. The mean age for positive labels was 8.5, the median was 8, and the range was 11. The mean age for negative labels was 12.6, the median was 14, and the range was 12. Of the respondents, 66% were White, 17% were Asian, 12% were African American or African American and White, and 8% were Other or White and Other. One student requested to be labeled as “Eastern European” and was placed under the “White” label for ease of analysis. Men comprised 51% of those sampled, women comprised 49%, 96% of respondents were educated in the United States, and 77% attended public school. Nearly 90% of the respondents participated in AP, 68% participated in Honors programs, 15% participated in IB, and 6% participated in other advanced programs (Figure 1). The average respondent was an 18.1year-old white man who was labeled as above average in intelligence by a teacher at the age of 8.5. “He” believed his teacher both at the time and now, went to a public school, participated in 1.7 advanced programs, and has a self-esteem score of 17/24. He got into 68% of his universities, and was accepted into 76% of his honors programs.
            The 6% (n=3) of respondents who were labeled negatively had higher levels of self-esteem (17.6/24) compared to the average student (17.3/24). Non-white students were recognized at earlier ages (7.3) compared to white students (8.8), and those with learning disabilities were recognized over two years earlier, at age 6.3.
            As seen in table 1, there was no strong or moderate positive correlation between the data other than what was directly related, such as number of schools applied to and number of schools admitted to (r=.57), and number of honors programs applied to and number of honors programs accepted to (r=.72). There were no strong negative correlations, and a few weak positive correlations between number of advanced programs that the student participated in and the number of schools the student was admitted to (r=.34). Other weak positive correlations included being Hispanic and the number of schools a student was admitted to (r=.32), and believing a label at the time and continuing to believe it (r=.33). There was a weak negative correlation between the number of honors programs applied to and the continuing belief in a label. All other correlations had an |r|<.3.
Conclusion
            The first hypothesis presented above was supported by the data in figure 4, which show the difference in percentage acceptance rate by age of labeling. Those who were labeled at or before age 10 had better outcomes than those who were labeled later in life. This has interesting implications when applied with the Pygmalion effect, as that would imply that simply by labeling the child they became smarter and more high-achieving than their later-blooming counterparts. Yet this is contrary to the Pomerantz and Kempner study, which linked praise and lower effort.
            The second hypothesis was not supported by the data, which showed slightly higher self-esteem in those who were labeled negatively, but this could be due to sampling error, as the sample size of those labeled negatively was 3, or it could be attributed to imperfect self-esteem measurement, as the researcher cut several questions from the self-esteem quiz. This will require more study to be effectively supported or not supported.
            Other forms of error include the small sample size, 53 out of the dorm capacity of 770; question bias, the informal setting in which the survey was administered, and human error in inputting and calculating the data. The demographic data also strayed from the university-wide demographics data from 2015, but that in itself if flawed, as there is no honors-specific data available other than what was collected in this research.
            This research can form the building blocks for further studies about labeling of high-achieving students, and can be drawn from and re-analyzed to form other conclusions about the population of the Honors College. This research also adds to the complexity of the effects of labeling in education, and shows the need for further research in the area.  
Bibliography
Ayers, Jane M., Lacy E. Krueger, and Beth A. Jones. 2015. "Effects of Labeling and Teacher Certification Type on Recall and Conflict Resolution." Journal of Educational Research 108 (6): 435-448.
Gold, Moniqueka E. and Heraldo Richards. 2012. "To Label Or Not to Label: The Special Education Question for African Americans. (Report)." Educational Foundations 26 (1-2): 143.
lo, C. O. 2014. "Labeling and Knowing: A Reconciliation of Implicit Theory and Explicit Theory among Students with Exceptionalities." Journal of Educational Research 107 (4): 281-298.
Pomerantz, Eva and Sara Kempner. 2013. "Mothers' Daily Person and Process Praise: Implications for Children's Theory of Intelligence and Motivation." Developmental Psychology 49 (11): 2040.
Restivo, Emily and Mark M. Lanier. 2015. "Measuring the Contextual Effects and Mitigating Factors of Labeling Theory." Justice Quarterly 32 (1): 116-141.
Rosenberg, M. 1965. Society and the Adolescent Self-Image: &nbsp;. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Rosenthal, Robert and Lenore Jacobson. 1968. Pygmalion in the Classroom. New York: Holt, Rinehart & Winston.
Shifrer, Dara. 2013. "Stigma of a Label: Educational Expectations for High School Students Labeled with Learning Disabilities." Journal of Health and Social Behavior 54 (4): 462-480.
Thompson, Gregory A. 2014. "Labeling in Interactional Practice: Applying Labeling Theory to Interactions and Interactional Analysis to Labeling." Symbolic Interaction 37 (4): 458-482.
Appendix

Table 1.
Table 2. 
 
Figure 1.
UNAVAILABLE
Figure 2.
UNAVAILABLE
Figure 3.







Figure 4.

UNAVAILABLE

Political Economy in India **DO NOT COPY**





FOREIGN AID IN INDIA




Gabriela Monasterio
Comparative Politics 1155
Paper 2: Question 2
November 28, 2016






Honorable President Pranab Mukherjee,
            I address you today to inform you of my position on foreign aid and national development for India. I hope that this briefing will help inform your decisions for India and her people.
            India has grown since its independence in 1947; it has transitioned from a socialist to a neo-liberal ideology, and we have grown to be more accepting of capitalism and foreign investment in recent years (Atul: 1998). Our country is the recipient of foreign aid, and that aid has been increasing over time, from 616 million USD in 1961 to 2.9 billion USD in 2014. There has been a slight decrease in our aid received recently, as our peak was 3.2 billion USD in 2011, but overall, there is a pattern of increased aid to our country (World Bank Group: 2016). We are trying to transition from an aid recipient to a donor, but now we are stuck in the middle. Our donations should exceed our received aid this fiscal year, but the world sees us as a “needy donor,” a state that is trying so hard to be liberal that it ignores its own domestic policies (Fuchs and Vadlamannati: 2013). In order to escape this label, we should forgo government-to-government aid, instead focusing our efforts on foreign investment and economic growth.
I believe that it is important for us to continue to provide aid despite our current status as an aid recipient because of the need for development in Southern Asia and the influence it gives us over the region. Publicly, of course, we must declare that it is only out of the goodness of our hearts, but behind closed doors, we will use the aid to curry favor. I have come to this conclusion by studying Lichbach and Zuckerman, whose culturalist, structuralist and rationalist perspectives I find intriguing. Their rationalist perspective calls for the cool interpretation of a situation, and choosing the “rational” or most logical and beneficial action (Lichbach and Zuckerman: 1997). A rationalist reading of India’s situation leads me to conclude that giving aid to our southern neighbors in South-South strategy is the best solution. We have already begun this strategy by supplying much of our aid to Bhutan and the Maldives, countries which are at a similar development level to India, but have much fewer resources. The only country in our region that we do not offer aid to is Pakistan, for obvious reasons. By doing this, we will gain an advantage over our needy neighbors, boosting our own economy as they give us more favorable trade and diplomatic agreements. If you think this is disingenuous, I would like to remind you of when the United Kingdom cried ingratitude at us for buying French planes instead of British ones, citing that one of their reasons for giving us aid was to entice us into purchasing their planes (The Logical Indian: 2015). We can, and should be influencing those around us, for our benefit and theirs. If we give other countries aid, they will be more likely to purchase goods and services from us, driving our economy. The best way for India to become a superpower in its own right is to have high and continuous economic growth (Sharma: 2013). Although Prime Minister Singh’s redistributive policies did help de-stratify the wealth in the early 2000’s, they did little to address the rapid rate of inflation and high deficits. His corrupt and inefficient policies that feed and employ millions cost our taxpayers billions annually. These policies of less redistribution and greater focus on the economy are also supported by William Easterly, in his piece To Help the Poor. Here, he shows that a GDP growth of just 1% will cause a 1% increase in the incomes of the lowest 20% of society (Easterly: 2001). This makes an excellent case for greater investment in India and the countries around us. The people obviously agree that economic growth is the only way out of poverty, as they voted the Bharatiya Janata Party in, a party that ran on renewed investment and completing key infrastructure projects (Manuel: 2014).
The aid we receive is as you have once said; “a peanut in our total development spending.”[1] The approximately 2 billion USD that we received annually in the early 2000’s is only 0.2% of India’s GDP (NORRAG: 2010). We spend most of our received aid on infrastructure, but much of it also goes to improving the lives of the Dalit, allowing them access to many services they were denied in the past (Jha and Swaroop: 1999). Those who worry that India would fall into ruin, becoming a society dominated by structuralist class struggles is misguided. They argue that government institutions are the only way to develop India, and by claiming this, they crush the people’s will. They are eroding our Hindu culture with their western safety nets, taking charity away from the people. The reforms implemented by NGOs and our government will not disappear. Dalit women will still be able to give birth in hospitals, and they will not soon forget the lessons of sanitation and empowerment that they were taught during India’s period as an aid recipient (Rowlett: 2015). India’s population will not stage a Marxist revolution if we take away foreign aid, and the only changes will be for the better.
Some say that redistribution is the only way for the lower classes to rise above the poverty level. They believe that economic growth is not enough to pull these people out of the depths of poverty, and that the government must intervene in the social and economic spheres. These people look through a culturalist lens, crying out that what works in one country will not necessarily work for India (despite the knowledge to the contrary), and they wish to take more time studying the problem, asking for more foreign aid. They reject the notion that economic growth will lead to prosperity. They are not content to let the government stay small, they wish to have it take over every facet of our lives. They are wholly and undeniably refuted by several of the greatest political scientists of our time, including Easterly as I have mentioned above, Collier, Fukuyama, and Smith.
Collier and Gunning argue that many countries in Africa have not grown at the rate they were expected to, mostly because of the factors surrounding them. The largest factor that they cite is lack of investment as well as failure to deliver basic services. They also note that “even widespread reforms in [public services] might not be sufficient to induce a recovery in private investment, since recent economic reforms are never fully credible.”[2] Collier and Gunning warn the Sub-Saharan countries, but they also warn us: reform now, or never recover (Collier and Gunning: 1999). Fukuyama rings true in much the same way in his piece The Necessity of Politics, warning us about the dangers of decaying states. India is beginning to fit some of Fukuyama’s criteria for a failed state, most obviously “failure to deliver basic services that people demand.”[3] (Fukuyama, 2011). According to the BBC, 40 percent of the world’s malnourished children live in India, and over 300 million Indians live on less than 1.25 USD per day (Rowlett, 2015). That is a failure of the government to provide the service of a stable, healthy life to its people, no matter their caste. Adam Smith’s argument in The Wealth of Nations is simple: remove government involvement, or limit it where it is necessary. By continuing to take foreign aid and using it to subsidize, we are increasing the involvement of the government in the free market, something that Smith says can only do harm (Smith: 1976). Even champion of Indian redistribution Atul Kohli admits that “the Indian state’s capacity to implement pro-poor, redistributive policies has always been quite limited”[4] and that cooperation would be critical at every level if redistribution is to be achieved successfully (Kohli: 1988). Redistribution would be costly, corruption-prone, and there is no guarantee that it would help the people. Even if economic growth does not help the poor as much as we hope, the economy would still be better off than it is now, and the nation will have greater development.
Keeping all of this in mind, I would recommend two things: first, to declare India closed to governmental aid, with the provision that all aid that other countries wish to be given to India be instead given to an NGO who wishes to work in India. We do not want the poorest of the poor to go ignored, and if foreigners are willing to touch the Dalit, let them. We will not turn down individual charity, but the government will take no part in the receiving or distributing of funds. This will eliminate the corruption associated with foreign aid, and it will most likely increase the help that our lower classes receive, as there is an inherent bias within our system. Second, I recommend further participation in investment banks such as the New Development Bank (NDB) and Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (AIIB). The loans provided by these banks can take the place of the aid we once received, and they will target more specific areas. The hard cash limit of the loans will discourage corruption, as every paise will matter. Indian companies will benefit from the competition for contracts, and our economy will experience a boon.
It is not unheard of for countries to refuse aid. In 2005, Eritrea cut itself off from most foreign aid, declining everything from food, to development loans, to grants from charities. Since then, Eritrea’s GDP has more than doubled, from about 1.1 billion USD to over 2.6 billion USD (World Bank Group, 2016). Measles and Polio have been eradicated, and the infant mortality rate has plummeted. The number of chronically hungry Eritreans is not being officially monitored, but the aid officials in Eritrea generally agree that food production levels have stayed consistent since the rejection of aid (Sanders: 2007). Some of this may be attributed to the increased efficiency due to Eritrea’s autocratic leader, but it is certain that their refusal of aid has not destroyed the poor country as many claimed it would. Surely a country as large and prosperous as India would do even better.
During and after natural disasters, it is quite common for countries to refuse foreign aid as well. Bangladesh refused aid after a garment factory collapsed, India rejected aid after an earthquake and tsunami in 2005, Pakistan rejected aid in 2015, and even the mighty United States rejected some foreign aid in the aftermath of hurricane Katrina. All of the aforementioned countries did so in a mix of lack of need and power plays. Bangladesh put out a call for help, but when they were denied the specific tools they needed most, they rejected all aid, claiming that they were doing a perfectly fine job without outside intervention. They arrested the building’s owner, and attempted to diffuse the situation by declaring a holiday for garment workers so that they could mourn and in hopes that their anger would fade (Doyle: 2013). As you know, we rejected the aid in hopes that the international community would redirect their aid to the countries that needed it more, like Sri Lanka, Indonesia and the Maldives. We also rejected the aid to show that we are a world power who does not need any help from anyone. “India wants to be seen as part of the solution, not part of the problem,”[5] and to protect that image, we rejected aid despite our own precedent of receiving aid in times of disaster (Luce: 2005). Pakistan rejected aid because they felt that they did not need the aid, as there was “no shortage of supplies.” (ANI: 2015). This was obviously an attempt to emulate India, the far superior country. The United States rejected some aid after hurricane Katrina, but most of it was simply squandered or tangled in bureaucratic red tape long enough that it became useless (Solomon: 2007). This was also a point of pride for them, but it also furthers my point that aid is best used by NGOs and not the government. The US government, long praised for its exemplary democracy, has failed its citizens in Louisiana. If the great United States has bureaucratic problems, how can we say that we are not also held up by red tape and malapportionment of funds? The only way to fix this is to remove aid entirely. We must forgo it for our own sake. Thank you.













References
ANI. "Earthquake in Pakistan: Foreign Aid for Quake Relief Work Rejected by PM Nawaz Sharif&nbsp;" Financial Express. The Indian Express, last modified Oct 29, accessed Nov 26, 2016, http://www.financialexpress.com/india-news/earthquake-in-pakistan-foreign-aid-for-quake-relief-work-rejected-by-pm-nawaz-sharif/158273/.
Doyle, Mark. 2013. "Bangladesh Defends Rejection of Foreign Aid for Collapse." BBC News, April 30,. http://www.bbc.com/news/world-asia-22347672.
Easterly, William. 2001. The Elusive Quest for Growth: Economists' Adventures and Misadventures in the Tropics&nbsp;. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press.
Fuchs, Andreas and Vadlamannati, Krishna C. "India - the Needy Donor." Aid Data. College of William and Mary, last modified Feb 6, accessed Nov 20, 2016, http://aiddata.org/blog/india-the-needy-donor.
Fukuyama, Francis. 2011. The Origins of Political Order: From Prehuman Times to the French Revolution. New York: Farrar, Strauss and Giroux.
Jha, Shikha and Vinaya Swaroop. 1999. "Foreign Aid to India: What does it Finance?" Economic and Political Weekly 34 (19): 1142-1146.
Kohli, Atul. 1998. Politics and Redistribution in India. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University.
Lichbach, Mark I. and Alan S. Zuckerman. 1997. Comparative Politics: Rationality, Culture, and Structure. New York: Cambrige University Press.
Luce, Edward. "India Defends Refusal to Accept Foreign Aid - FT.Com." Financial Times. The Financial Times, last modified Jan 5, accessed Nov 27, 2016, https://www.ft.com/content/90300afe-5f3d-11d9-8cca-00000e2511c8.
Manuel, Anja. "Why India has Less Inequality than U.S." Reuters. Reuters, last modified May 8, accessed Nov 23, 2016, http://blogs.reuters.com/great-debate/2014/05/08/why-india-has-less-inequality-than-u-s/.
NORRAG. "A Brave New World of 'Emerging', 'Non-DAC' Donors and their Differences from Traditional Donors." NORRAG. Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies, last modified Sept, accessed Nov 26, 2016, http://www.norrag.org/es/publications/boletin-norrag/online-version/a-brave-new-world-of-emerging-non-dac-donors-and-their-differences-from-traditional-donors/detail/emerging-aid-donors-india.html.
Paul Collier and Jan Willem Gunning. 1999. "Why has Africa Grown Slowly?" The Journal of Economic Perspectives 13 (3): 3-22. doi:10.1257/jep.13.3.3. http://www.jstor.org/stable/2646982.
Rowlett, Justin. "UK Ending Aid to India: Where does the Money Go?" BBC., last modified Oct 7, accessed Nov 25, 2016, http://www.bbc.com/news/world-asia-india-34398449.
Sanders, Edmund. 2007. "Eritrea Aspires to be Self-Reliant, Rejecting Foreign Aid." Los Angeles Times, Oct 2,. http://www.latimes.com/world/la-fg-eritrea2oct02-story.html.
Sharma, Ghanshyam. "India Needs Economic Growth, Not Redistribution." Centre Right India., last modified Oct 12, accessed Nov 18, 2016, http://centreright.in/2013/10/india-needs-economic-growth-not-redistribution/#.WDsDtuYrKM_.
Smith, Adam. 1976. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations&nbsp;, edited by Edwin Cannan. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Solomon, John and Spencer S. Hsu. 2007. "Most Katrina Aid from Overseas Went Unclaimed." The Washington Post, April 29,. http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2007/04/28/AR2007042801113.html.
The Logical Indian. "Know Everything about how Much India Receives and Donates Foreign Aid." The Logical Indian. Creatiwox Internet, last modified Nov 6, accessed Nov 19, 2016, https://thelogicalindian.com/story-feed/exclusive/know-everything-about-how-much-india-receives-and-donates-foreign-aid/.
World Bank Group. "GDP (Current US$)." The World Bank., accessed Nov 25, 2016, http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.MKTP.CD?locations=ER.
———. 2016b. Net Official Development Assistance and Official Aid Received (Current US$) The World Bank.



[1] Rowlett, Justin. "UK Ending Aid to India: Where does the Money Go?" BBC., last modified Oct 7, accessed Nov 25, 2016, http://www.bbc.com/news/world-asia-india-34398449.
[2] Paul Collier and Jan Willem Gunning. 1999. "Why has Africa Grown Slowly?" The Journal of Economic Perspectives 13 (3): 3-22. doi:10.1257/jep.13.3.3. http://www.jstor.org/stable/2646982.
[3] Fukuyama, Francis. 2011. The Origins of Political Order: From Prehuman Times to the French Revolution. New York: Farrar, Strauss and Giroux.
[4] Kohli, Atul. 1998. Politics and Redistribution in India. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University.
[5] Luce, Edward. "India Defends Refusal to Accept Foreign Aid - FT.Com." Financial Times. The Financial Times, last modified Jan 5, accessed Nov 27, 2016, https://www.ft.com/content/90300afe-5f3d-11d9-8cca-00000e2511c8.

13th Movie as it relates to India **DO NOT COPY**

13th raises issues of prison population in India because India has the fifth highest prison population, at over 380,000 people and with the prisons running at 117% capacity, higher than the US’ 107%. The prison population in India increased by over 100,000 people between 200 and 2006, but only increased by about 10,000 between 2006 and 2012[1]. This shows a slowing of the imprisonment of Muslims, Dalits and Adivasis (the three most exploited groups), but there is still an insane amount of people being imprisoned. India also has a history of treating those awaiting trial the same as those who have been convicted, which is to say badly. Although the Indian Constitution mandates that the detainees be produced in front of a magistrate within 24 hours of arrest, most of their appearances result in the extension of their custody buy the police, usually without counsel or any real protest. The “undertrials” as they are called, spend months awaiting trials- trials that commonly end in acquittal[2]. Hundreds of Indians are given the death penalty, inconsistent with precedence, forcing a long appeals process that leaves inmates wondering if today will be their last[3]. Even those not sentenced to death fear for their lives. Some 111 deaths and 21 “disappearances” occurred in a five-year period from 1984 to 1989 in the state of Andhra Pradesh, all in police lock-ups. This mirrors what is exposed in “13th”, and could lead to a similar line of investigation into the Indian penal system, despite the Supreme Court’s new focus on reforming the system[4].
Structuralist and culturalist perspectives seem the most compelling, as there is nothing rational about imprisoning a race in a flight of fancy. As discussed in the documentary, the South was devastated after the Civil War, and the abolition of slavery only exacerbated this, destroying their weakened economy. The free prison labor became ingrained in the structures of the South, just as slavery had been, and it was simply an extension of slavery to incarcerate tens of thousands of blacks. Culturalists would look at Nixon’s Chief of Domestic Policy’s statement about targeting blacks, the campaigns from Reconstruction onward that focused on safety, segregation and disenfranchisement and would conclude that discrimination against blacks was so ingrained in American society that the current system is inevitable.
Hobsbawm’s Nationalism informed my perspective, showing why it has been so hard to initiate change in American society. The black community has intellectuals, no doubt, but they feel removed from their poorer brethren and cannot spread the knowledge of why the community is being repressed as well as one who is ingrained in the community. Because the force that they are fighting is their nation, because they are overwhelmingly disenfranchised, because their leaders are imprisoned, and because they are not a unified front, blacks cannot express nationalism in the same way that the French did in the 1780s and 90s. Zakaria’s A Brief History of Human Liberty also informed my viewing. His piece describes how conflict and competition of powers increases liberty, which allowed me to see that because there has not been a real conflict over the governance of the black community since the Civil War, their liberty has no reason to have increased in that time. Many of their advancements were a result of the Civil Rights movement, led by Martin Luther King Jr., who competed with the President for social control of the black community, not the actual control.
I would endorse the current actions that the Indian Supreme Court is taking- comprehensive reform and oversight. I would recommend that they expand the reform, adding to it a system for public defenders (or their equivalent) to be compensated for their work (they aren’t at the time of writing). Removal of the caste system would also improve the prison system, eliminating the ingrained prejudices that lead to maltreatment of the lower castes and preferential treatment for the upper middle class.

























Bibliography
Doshi, Vidhi. 2016. "India's Death Row Prisoners Face Horrific Conditions, Study Finds." The Guardian, May 6,.https://www.theguardian.com/world/2016/may/06/india-death-row-prisoners-horrific-conditions-study.
Human Rights Watch. 1991. Prison Conditions in India Human Rights Watch.
San, Shreeja. 2016. "Supreme Court Kicks Off Prison Reforms." Live Mint, Feb 06,.http://www.livemint.com/Politics/2GQAbPa6Wm2IeK4z1I6CUN/Supreme-Court-kicks-off-prison-reforms.html.
Subodh Varma. 2014. "Muslims, Dalits and Tribals make Up 53% of all Prisoners in India." The Times of India, Nov 25,.http://search.proquest.com/docview/1627142907.
World Prison Brief, Institute for Criminal Policy Research. "World Prison Brief Data: India." World Prison Breif.,http://www.prisonstudies.org/country/india.





[1] World Prison Brief, Institute for Criminal Policy Research. "World Prison Brief Data: India." World Prison Breif.,http://www.prisonstudies.org/country/india.
[2] Human Rights Watch. 1991. Prison Conditions in India Human Rights Watch.
[3] Doshi, Vidhi. 2016. "India's Death Row Prisoners Face Horrific Conditions, Study Finds." The Guardian, May 6,.https://www.theguardian.com/world/2016/may/06/india-death-row-prisoners-horrific-conditions-study.
[4] San, Shreeja. 2016. "Supreme Court Kicks Off Prison Reforms." Live Mint, Feb 06,.http://www.livemint.com/Politics/2GQAbPa6Wm2IeK4z1I6CUN/Supreme-Court-kicks-off-prison-reforms.html.